Priceless: Curing the Healthcare Crisis

Priceless: Curing the Healthcare Crisis

by John C. Goodman
ISBN-10:
1598130838
ISBN-13:
9781598130836
Pub. Date:
06/01/2012
Publisher:
Independent Institute, The
ISBN-10:
1598130838
ISBN-13:
9781598130836
Pub. Date:
06/01/2012
Publisher:
Independent Institute, The
Priceless: Curing the Healthcare Crisis

Priceless: Curing the Healthcare Crisis

by John C. Goodman
$28.95
Current price is , Original price is $28.95. You
$28.95 
  • SHIP THIS ITEM
    Temporarily Out of Stock Online
  • PICK UP IN STORE

    Your local store may have stock of this item.

  • SHIP THIS ITEM

    Temporarily Out of Stock Online

    Please check back later for updated availability.


Overview

In the groundbreaking book Priceless, renowned healthcare economist John Goodman reveals how patients, healthcare providers, employers, and employees are all trapped in a dysfunctional, bureaucratic, healthcare system fraught with perverse incentives that raise costs, reduce quality, and make care less accessible. Unless changed, these incentives will only worsen the problems in the coming months and years. He demonstrates how market forces have been driven out from the American healthcare system, making it nearly impossible to solve problems as effectively or efficiently as in virtually every other type of consumer marketplace. Goodman cuts through the politics to think "outside the box" and propose dozens of bold and crucial innovations that, if adopted, would enable caregivers, entrepreneurs, and patients to use their knowledge and creativity to create access to low-cost, high-quality healthcare.

Product Details

ISBN-13: 9781598130836
Publisher: Independent Institute, The
Publication date: 06/01/2012
Pages: 392
Product dimensions: 6.30(w) x 9.10(h) x 1.30(d)

About the Author

John C. Goodman is a research fellow at the Independent Institute and a Kellye Wright Fellow in Health Care at the National Center for Policy Analysis, of which he is president. He is the author of more than 50 studies on health policy, retirement reform, and tax issues, as well as nine books, including Leaving Women Behind: Modern Families, Outdated Laws; Lives at Risk: Single Payer National Health Insurance Around the World; and The Patient Power: Solving America's Health Care Crisis. His articles have been featured in publications such as Health Affairs, National Review, and the Wall Street Journal. He lives in Dallas, Texas.

Read an Excerpt

Priceless

Curing the Healthcare Crisis


By John C. Goodman

The Independent Institute

Copyright © 2012 The Independent Institute
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-1-59813-084-3



CHAPTER 1

Introduction


FORGET EVERYTHING YOU know about healthcare for a moment. I want to introduce you to a new way of thinking about it.

Our healthcare system is an example of what social scientists call complex systems. These systems are so complicated that no one person can ever fully grasp everything that is going on. As individuals, all we ever really see is a small slice of the system. That's usually the part of it we experience.

For example, the typical patient sees a doctor only a handful of times during any given year. A primary care doctor takes care of only about 2,500 patients. These interactions are important, but when we stop to realize that there are 300 million potential patients and 800,000 doctors, it's clear that the perspective of any one doctor or any one patient is extremely limited.

Other markets in our economy are also examples of complex systems, but healthcare is many times more complex than a normal market. The reason: in addition to garden-variety economic forces, the medical marketplace is institutionalized, bureaucratized, and extensively regulated. Doctors are heavily influenced by medical ethics and traditional ways of doing things. Almost everything they do is affected by third-party payer bureaucracies (insurance companies, employers, and government) and by regulations that are inconsistent, voluminous, and complex. They also face the ever-present threat of tort law litigation.

To make matters even more complicated, we have completely suppressed normal market processes in healthcare — in this country and all over the developed world. As a result, in healthcare few people ever see a real price for anything. Employees never see a premium reflecting the real cost of their health insurance. Patients almost never see a real price for their medical care. Even at the family doctor's office, it's hard to discover what anything costs. For something complicated, like a hip replacement, the information is virtually impossible to obtain — at least in advance of the operation.

On the supply side, doctors and hospitals are rarely paid real prices for the services they render. Instead, they are paid on the basis of reimbursement formulas. Each payer may have a different formula. Medicare (for the elderly and the disabled) pays one set of fees. Medicaid (for the poor) pays another. BlueCross pays yet a third. All of the other insurers and all of the employer plans may also have separately negotiated fees. As a result, there really is no market-clearing price that brings supply and demand together in a way we experience in other sectors. Enormous amounts of money change hands every day in the medical marketplace, but most of the conventional rules of economics do not directly apply.

An interesting characteristic of complex systems is that when you perturb them (by passing a law, for example), there are always unintended consequences. The less you know about the system, the more unpredictable these consequences can be. Economic history provides numerous examples of governments that adopted policies in an attempt to improve things but ended up making the situation worse. Unfortunately, this happens in healthcare all the time.

For example, one of the goals of many public policies adopted in this country and around the world is to remove price as a barrier to care. Ideal health insurance is often said to be health insurance with no deductible or co-payment, making medical care essentially free at the point of delivery. Yet, if patients have no out-of-pocket costs their economic incentive will be to overuse the system, essentially consuming healthcare until the last amount obtained has a value that approaches zero. Also, if patients are not paying money for the services they receive, they're not likely to shop around for the best buy, so doctors, hospitals, and other providers will not compete for patients based on price, They will have no economic incentive to keep costs low — the way producers behave in other markets. To the contrary, the incentive of the providers will be to maximize against the payment formulas in order to enhance their incomes.

Well-intentioned public policies designed to make healthcare affordable for individuals, therefore, have had the surprising effect of causing healthcare spending to become unaffordable for the nation as a whole. Rising healthcare spending is the principal cause of our out-of-control federal deficit. It is bankrupting cities, counties, and state governments. It has created huge unfunded liabilities for some of our largest corporations. It is contributing to the stagnation in worker take-home pay. It can potentially bankrupt the families of individuals who have the misfortune to become ill — even those with health insurance.

Another well-intentioned public policy initiative — adopted by some states — is to try to make health insurance affordable for people with pre-existing conditions by requiring insurers to charge the same premium to all buyers, regardless of health status. Yet, this legislation has the unintended consequence of encouraging people to remain uninsured until they get sick. As healthy people drop out of the market and only people with health problems remain, the premium needed to cover the insurers' cost begins to soar. In the state of New York, this sort of regulation has produced staggeringly high premiums. For a run-of-the-mill individual policy, United Healthcare Oxford charges a premium of $1,855.97 a month, or more than $22,000 a year. For a family, the premium is $5,707.11 per month, or more than $68,000 a year. A policy designed to make insurance affordable, therefore, is pricing thousands of people out of the market.

Federal health programs provide other examples of unintended consequences of public policies foisted on a complex system. In 1965, Congress passed Medicare in an attempt to increase access to healthcare for the elderly and improve their health status. Members of Congress believed they could do so without any material impact on the rest of the healthcare system. Yet MIT professor Amy Finkelstein has discovered that the passage of Medicare had no effect on the health of the elderly — at least as measured by mortality — but the additional spending set off a bout of healthcare inflation for all patients — one that never subsided.

In 2003, Congress passed a Medicare drug benefit, largely out of concern that senior citizens couldn't afford the coverage themselves. Since the new program (Medicare Part D) had no funding source, Congress created a $15.6 trillion unfunded liability for the federal government, looking indefinitely into the future — more than the unfunded liability in Social Security. Yet economist Andrew Rettenmaier discovered that only 7 percent of the benefits actually bought new drugs for seniors. The other 93 percent simply transferred to government (and taxpayers) the bill for drugs the elderly or their insurers were already buying. Only one in every thirteen dollars represented a new drug purchase. Interestingly, the help given to the small number of people who were not otherwise getting medications actually reduced Medicare's spending, as drugs were substituted for more expensive doctor and hospital therapies. But this profit on the truly needy was overwhelmed by the cost of giving the benefit to those who didn't need it — a cost that has created an enormous obligation for current and future taxpayers.

Here are two other unintended consequences of health policies designed to make healthcare free at the point of delivery. In other markets, producers don't compete only on price. They compete on quality as well. In healthcare, however, it appears that when providers don't compete on price, they often don't compete on quality either. That may be one reason why critics find that the quality of care we receive (including the very large number of avoidable errors and other adverse medical events) falls far short of what we would expect in a normal market.

Also, in most markets, we pay for goods and services with both time and money, and producers and sellers understand that we value our time as well as our pocket book. Public policies designed to suppress the role of money as a medium of exchange in the medical marketplace, however, have had the inadvertent consequence of increasing the importance of waiting times and other non-price barriers to care. These efforts to increase access to care may well have decreased access instead by making people wait longer to get appointments and to see the doctor once they reach her office.


How We Are Trapped

The premise of the book is that most of our problems arise because we are trapped. We are caught up in a dysfunctional system in which perverse economic incentives cause all of us to do things that raise the cost of care, lower its quality, and make access to care more difficult. Perverse incentives are faced by everyone: patients, doctors, nurses, hospital administrators, employees, employers, and so on. As we interact with the system, most of us spot ways to solve problems. We see things we could individually do to avoid waste and make care less expensive, for example. But the system generally penalizes us for doing the right things and rewards us for doing the wrong things. Anything we do as individuals to eliminate waste generally benefits someone other than ourselves.

So what's the answer? Let people out of the trap. Liberate them from the dysfunctionality that is causing us so much trouble.

This message is precisely the opposite of what you are likely to hear from other health policy experts — on the right and the left. The conventional view is that we have too much freedom, not too little. Doctors are said to have too much freedom to provide treatments that are not "best practice" or that are not "evidenced-based." Patients are said to have too much freedom to patronize doctors and facilities with inferior performance records.

Hence, the conventional solution: put even more restrictions on what doctors can do and where patients can go for their care. Ultimately, the conventional answer to the country's health policy problems is to have government tell doctors how to practice medicine and to tell patients what care they can have and where they can get it.

The biggest problem with this approach is that it would leave us even more trapped than we currently are. Incentives would be even more perverse. We would have a plan designed by folks in Washington. But 300 million potential patients, 800,000 doctors, almost 2.5 million registered nurses, and thousands of others working in the system would find it in their self-interest to undermine the plan. My answer is just the opposite. I want all those patients and all those doctors to discover it is in their self-interest to solve problems, not create them.

Under the conventional approach, every doctor, every nurse, every hospital administrator will get up every morning and ask, "How can I squeeze more money out of the payment formulas today?"

My answer is just the opposite. Under the approach I will recommend, all these people will be encouraged to start each day by asking, "How can I make my service better, less costly, and more accessible to patients today?"


Getting Out of the Trap: Emerging Entrepreneurs

That we need a new way of thinking is almost self-evident. After all, healthcare has been recognized as one of our most important national policy problems for over a quarter of a century. It has spawned thousands of conferences, briefings, speeches, legislative hearings, books, essays, and scholarly articles. It provoked legislation that envisions a complete overhaul of the system in just a few years. Yet even with all of this, we are no closer to a genuine solution to our problems than we were twenty-five years ago.

In complex systems, there are always unmet needs and problems to be solved. The more dysfunctional the system, the more numerous are the unmet needs and the more severe are the problems. In other sectors, needs to be met and problems to be solved are the fertile ground from which entrepreneurs emerge. Where is healthcare's equivalent of a Bill Gates or a Steve Jobs?

The answer: There are literally thousands of entrepreneurs in healthcare. I meet them every day. In fact, I believe I can safely say that there is no serious problem in the business of health that is not already being substantially solved in some way by an entrepreneur somewhere in the system. Unfortunately, these efforts tend to be scattered and limited. Most of the time they run into three major barriers: insurance companies, employers, and government.

These are the three entities that pay most of the healthcare bills. They are the third-party payers. (The first two parties are the doctor and the patient.) With respect to healthcare, they tend to be bureaucratic, wedded to tradition, and resistant to change. They are, in a word, the entrepreneur's nemesis.

Take the subject of hospital costs. It is well known that the cost of procedures varies radically from hospital to hospital, as does the quality of care. So why not take advantage of this fact? In this book, I am going to argue that a version of what some call value-based health insurance could cut the typical health plan's hospital costs in half. How does it work? The insurer pays the cost of care at a low-cost, high-quality facility (which may require the patient to travel) and only that amount. Patients are free to go to another facility but must pay the full extra cost of their choice.

Now, I wasn't the first person to think of this. In fact, an Austin, Texas-based company, Employer Direct Healthcare, is offering employers a variation on that idea at this very moment. They negotiate rates with select hospitals that are from one-third to one-half lower than what other health insurers are paying. Most insurers are at the opposite end of the smart-buying spectrum, however. BlueCross of Texas, for example, not only does not steer patients to one hospital rather than another, there is not a single hospital in Dallas that is not in its network.

Part of the reason why the insurers are so resistant to cost-reducing innovations is that many of their employer clients are also resistant. The typical client of Employer Direct Healthcare, for example, waives the deductible and copayment for patients who choose the low-cost, high-quality facilities, but that is the full extent of the financial incentive. A step in the right direction perhaps, but a timid one. An aggressive strategy would be to let the employee pay the full extra cost of their choices.

Of the three third-party payer institutions, government is by far the worst at resisting entrepreneurship — even when the government itself is implementing radical change. As part of the Affordable Care Act (ACA), for example, states are to establish health insurance exchanges, allowing individuals to electronically select their health insurance from among competing plans. The federal government is offering millions of dollars to set up these exchanges. In some states, officials are arguing about how to spend the money, and in other states, they are actually refusing the money on the grounds that it amounts to acceptance of a health reform they do not like.

But why does any state need to spend millions to set up an exchange? Did you know that eHealth already has an electronic exchange, and more than 1 million people have health insurance purchased online through its system? The Obama administration is asking fifty state governments to spend a great deal of money to invent something that a private company has already discovered — and is ready to implement for the government for pennies on the dollar.

The administration is also spending millions of dollars trying to encourage electronic medical records. But did you know that eHealth already offers many of its customers an electronic medical record (including a record of doctor visits, prescriptions taken, etc.), based on insurance payment records?

Although we often associate the term entrepreneur with profit seeking, the healthcare field is teeming with innovators who are largely motivated by altruism. Take Dr. Jeffrey Brenner of Camden, New Jersey. In any other field, Brenner would be a millionaire, but because he's in healthcare, he doesn't know how he's going to make ends meet. Like entrepreneurs in every market, Brenner thought outside the box. He discovered an ingenious way of lowering healthcare costs: focus on the "hot spots" of medicine — the high-use, high-spending patients — and solve their problems with unconventional care.


(Continues...)

Excerpted from Priceless by John C. Goodman. Copyright © 2012 The Independent Institute. Excerpted by permission of The Independent Institute.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Table of Contents

Preface xiii

1 Introduction 1

Part I Why We Are Trapped

2 How Healthcare Is Different 13

3 Why People Disagree About Health Policy 39

Part II The Consequences of Being Trapped

4 What Being Trapped Means to You 55

5 Why Do We Spend So Much on Healthcare? 67

6 Why Is There a Problem with Quality? 95

7 Why Is There a Problem with Access to Care? 107

8 Why Can't You Buy Real Health Insurance? 123

Part III Letting People Out of the Trap

9 Empowering Patients 143

10 Liberating Institutions 158

11 Designing Ideal Health Insurance 171

12 Solving the Problem of Patient Safety 189

13 The Do-No-Harm Approach to Public Policy 201

Part IV Letting Government Out of the Trap

14 Reforming Medicare 221

15 Reforming Medicaid 244

16 Understanding the New Healthcare Law 257

17 What Most Needs Repealing and Replacing in the New Healthcare Law 287

18 Conclusion 309

Notes 315

Index 355

About the Author 371

What People are Saying About This

Richard A. Epstein

John Goodman's terrific book Priceless . . . offers a breath of fresh air in a tired healthcare debate that demonstrates once again that markets enjoy their greatest advantage in complex settings that call for imaginative solutions that no government-driven system can deliver.
—Richard A. Epstein - Laurence A. Tisch Professor of Law New York University

June E. O'Neill

Priceless provides fresh and original insights to help steer us into a system that harnesses individual choice, aligns price and quality, and more effectively utilizes financing to achieve these ends.
—June E. O'Neill, former Director, Congressional Budget Office; Wollman Distinguished Professor of Economics and Director of the Center for the Study of Business and Government, Baruch College

Peter R. Orszag

There's no question that today's healthcare system is littered with distorted incentives and what John Goodman calls dysfunctionality. Priceless is a call to arms to do something about it.
—Peter R. Orszag, former Director, Congressional Budget Office

Mitch Daniels

John Goodman has long been the clearest and most insightful healthcare thinker we have...it's time we acted on his common sense, fact-based wisdom in Priceless.
—Mitch Daniels, Governor of Indiana

Uwe E. Reinhardt

If liberal commentators wish to sharpen their claws, there is no better stone on which to do it than John Goodman's book Priceless.
—Uwe E. Reinhardt, James Madison Professor of Political Economy, Princeton University

Paul Ryan

I have been following John Goodman's health policy ideas for as long as I've been on Capitol Hill. John's latest effort, Priceless: Curing the Health Care Crisis, makes it abundantly clear why he is a source of wisdom, insight, and innovative thinking.
—Paul Ryan, Chairman, U.S. House Budget Committee

Gail R. Wilensky

John Goodman, widely known as the father of health savings accounts, is as provocative and controversial as ever in his book, Priceless . . . interesting for all who have been frustrated in their search for a workable solution to our healthcare woes.
—Gail R. Wilensky, former Administrator, Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services

From the B&N Reads Blog

Customer Reviews