Side Effects: Mexican Governance Under NAFTA's Labor and Environmental Agreements
This is a story about governance in Mexico after the labor and environmental accords—called "side agreements"—that accompanied the NAFTA treaty went into effect. These side agreements required member states to uphold and enforce their labor and environmental laws; though never codified, it was widely accepted that Mexico, in particular, had a problem with law enforcement. Side Effects explores how differences in institutional design (of the side agreements) and domestic capacity (between the labor and environment sectors) influenced norm socialization in Mexico. It argues that the acceptance of rule-of-law norms in environmental governance can be attributed to participating institutions' independence from national control, their willingness to give citizens access, and the professionalization and technical capacity of domestic bureaucrats and civil society actors. Changes in labor governance have been hampered by union confederations, longstanding corruption, and a closed opportunity structure. Going beyond a simple accounting exercise of resources devoted to enforcing the law, this book comes to grips with how best to strengthen local capacity and promote pro-norm behavior—advances essential to the task of development and democratization.
1111566101
Side Effects: Mexican Governance Under NAFTA's Labor and Environmental Agreements
This is a story about governance in Mexico after the labor and environmental accords—called "side agreements"—that accompanied the NAFTA treaty went into effect. These side agreements required member states to uphold and enforce their labor and environmental laws; though never codified, it was widely accepted that Mexico, in particular, had a problem with law enforcement. Side Effects explores how differences in institutional design (of the side agreements) and domestic capacity (between the labor and environment sectors) influenced norm socialization in Mexico. It argues that the acceptance of rule-of-law norms in environmental governance can be attributed to participating institutions' independence from national control, their willingness to give citizens access, and the professionalization and technical capacity of domestic bureaucrats and civil society actors. Changes in labor governance have been hampered by union confederations, longstanding corruption, and a closed opportunity structure. Going beyond a simple accounting exercise of resources devoted to enforcing the law, this book comes to grips with how best to strengthen local capacity and promote pro-norm behavior—advances essential to the task of development and democratization.
17.49 In Stock
Side Effects: Mexican Governance Under NAFTA's Labor and Environmental Agreements

Side Effects: Mexican Governance Under NAFTA's Labor and Environmental Agreements

by Mark Aspinwall
Side Effects: Mexican Governance Under NAFTA's Labor and Environmental Agreements

Side Effects: Mexican Governance Under NAFTA's Labor and Environmental Agreements

by Mark Aspinwall

eBook

$17.49  $24.95 Save 30% Current price is $17.49, Original price is $24.95. You Save 30%.

Available on Compatible NOOK devices, the free NOOK App and in My Digital Library.
WANT A NOOK?  Explore Now

Related collections and offers


Overview

This is a story about governance in Mexico after the labor and environmental accords—called "side agreements"—that accompanied the NAFTA treaty went into effect. These side agreements required member states to uphold and enforce their labor and environmental laws; though never codified, it was widely accepted that Mexico, in particular, had a problem with law enforcement. Side Effects explores how differences in institutional design (of the side agreements) and domestic capacity (between the labor and environment sectors) influenced norm socialization in Mexico. It argues that the acceptance of rule-of-law norms in environmental governance can be attributed to participating institutions' independence from national control, their willingness to give citizens access, and the professionalization and technical capacity of domestic bureaucrats and civil society actors. Changes in labor governance have been hampered by union confederations, longstanding corruption, and a closed opportunity structure. Going beyond a simple accounting exercise of resources devoted to enforcing the law, this book comes to grips with how best to strengthen local capacity and promote pro-norm behavior—advances essential to the task of development and democratization.

Product Details

ISBN-13: 9780804784788
Publisher: Stanford University Press
Publication date: 01/09/2013
Sold by: Barnes & Noble
Format: eBook
Pages: 232
File size: 2 MB

About the Author

About The Author
Mark Aspinwall is Professor of Politics at the University of Edinburgh.

Read an Excerpt

SIDE EFFECTS

Mexican Governance Under NAFTA's Labor and Environmental Agreements
By Mark Aspinwall

Stanford University Press

Copyright © 2013 the Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University
All right reserved.

ISBN: 978-0-8047-8229-6


Chapter One

A Tale of Two Side Agreements

ON OCTOBER 4, 1992, PRESIDENTIAL CANDIDATE BILL CLINTON gave a speech at North Carolina State University in which he took a position in favor of the recently negotiated North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). Yet he faced a dilemma. On the one hand, he called for Americans to embrace the global economy and wider economic integration. Indeed, much of his campaign strategy was focused on the economy—even as he spoke, a now-famous sign hung on the wall in his Little Rock campaign headquarters that read (in part): "It's the economy, stupid." The election was fought in the context of recession, and economic policy was Clinton's main weapon.

But on the other hand, Clinton also made direct reference to environmental and labor standards being violated in Mexico and to the fact that the agreement negotiated by President George H. W. Bush did nothing to address these problems. He vowed to create supplementary institutions to guarantee enforcement of standards, as well as encourage capacity to be developed through cooperative activities between the partners. Once elected, Clinton followed through on his promise and established two "side agreements," the North American Agreement on Environmental Cooperation (NAAEC) and the North American Agreement on Labor Cooperation (NAALC). They were signed in September 1993, despite the irritation of the Canadian and Mexican governments, who thought they had secured a deal and who were not happy about bearing the cost of Clinton's campaign promises.

This book looks at what happened next. It examines the impact of NAFTA's side agreements on Mexican governance and the conditions under which a pro–rule of law norm has been absorbed by environmental and labor authorities. The side agreements require member states to uphold and enforce their labor and environmental laws. It was widely acknowledged (though never codified in the side agreements) that it was Mexico in particular that had a problem with law enforcement and might enjoy an unfair trade advantage by failing to enforce its own laws and regulatory standards. Under the new side agreements, Mexico could no longer turn a blind eye to the fl outing of its own rules.

We begin with a puzzle. External scrutiny (through the NAFTA side agreements) and domestic oversight (through strengthened courts and freedom of information) brought equivalent pressures to both the environmental and labor sectors. But pro–rule of law norms have been internalized to a greater extent in Mexican environmental agencies than in the labor agencies. Given that they were subjected to the same pressures, why did they not adapt at the same rate?

Most analysts of rule of law take the state as the unit of analysis, meaning that change happens to the state as a whole, rather than to certain parts of the state, such as sectoral ministries. No intrastate variation in rule of law is accounted for. For example, international relations (IR) theorists claim that variations in external "mechanisms of socialization" (such as persuasion and shaming) are responsible for variations in the rate at which domestic actors absorb ideas about rights and governance (Checkel 2001, 2005; Johnston 2001). Economists theorize that only states with long-term systems of equality and absence of abuse of authority will sustain rule of law (Weingast 2009).

Similarities between the environmental and labor cases allow a number of potentially important variables to be controlled, and we thus have an excellent natural experiment, enabling us to draw far more fine-grained conclusions about what causes changes to attitudes about rule of law in developing states and how regional agreements can play a part. It is important that we not lose the opportunity to compare these cases. Broader multistate studies of norm change (Risse and Sikkink 1999) and empirical analyses of rule of law (World Justice Project 2011; Kaufmann et al. 2009; United States Institute of Peace 2011) that use the state as the unit of analysis cannot provide this level of nuance.

I have two overarching aims in this book. The first aim is to examine the capacity-building and institutional development effects of the NAFTA side agreements. There is no comprehensive treatment of capacity-building and institutional development, even though it is an important aim. In fact, most accounts conclude that the institutions created by NAFTA to oversee enforcement of environmental and labor rules have failed to live up to expectations (Hufbauer and Schott 2005). From a policy perspective, understanding how the design of regional institutions affects institutional development and capacity building is important, given the growth of regional trade agreements and the inclusion of emerging and developing countries within them.

The second aim is theoretical. I seek to contribute to a more general understanding of how differences in institutional design (of the side agreements) and differences in domestic capacity (between the labor and environment sectors) influenced norm socialization. I argue that the relevant design and capacity factors are, first, the independence of the side agreement institutions from national control and the extent to which they permit citizen access and, second, the levels of professionalization and technical capacity of domestic bureaucrats and civil society actors. Professionalization is affected by the level of mobility of actors across professional boundaries (especially from civil society to ministerial positions), the permeability of domestic institutions, leadership within bureaucracies, and the level of politicization of civil ser vice positions.

The most important policy lessons from this study are that regional agreements seeking to improve norms of good governance in developing states need to incorporate (1) citizen complaint mechanisms, (2) opportunities for in de pen dent regional authorities to create public factual records that highlight transgressions, (3) means by which civil society can influence the work agenda of the regional institution, and (4) capacity-building resources for domestic authorities and civil society groups.

Domestic authorities should encourage (1) parallel institutions at the national level, such as transparency authorities and in de pen dent judiciaries, that reinforce external normative pressures; (2) education and training programs for civil society actors and bureaucrats; (3) opportunities for inward mobility into bureaucracies for trained nongovernmental organization (NGO) personnel; and (4) more secure (depoliticized) career paths for senior civil servants to retain technical capacity within government. Relatively low-cost extrastate institutions with oversight powers, the ability to communicate directly with domestic NGOs, and in de pen dent reporting powers can be surprisingly effective in leveraging normative pressures on governments.

The study reveals that although there has been governance change in both areas, environmental governance has improved more. Rule of law norms are more widely accepted, and technical capacity among civil society and government officials has been strengthened. Mexico has made use of the environmental side agreement to improve federal institutions, upgrade the quality of environmental information, encourage civil society, and develop the border. Mexican environmental bureaucrats now think differently about their own environmental rules. In the labor sector, powerful, government-connected union confederations have for de cades controlled unionization and helped repress workers' rights, restricting the normative socialization effect of the labor side agreement. Although some in de pen dent unions, labor NGOs, lawyers, and activists have tried to use the NAFTA labor accord to bring rule of law to Mexican labor practice, the path de pen den cy of long-standing corruption and closed opportunity structure prevents a relatively weak external force from exerting enough pressure to bring about adaptation.

These issues are critically important for development and demo cratization. Transnational markets bring increasing pressures to standardize norms and rules (Bruszt and McDermott forthcoming). Trade agreements formalize compliance pressures. New trade agreements have been concluded (both by the United States and by other developed states) that contain extratrade provisions on environmental, labor, and other regulatory standards. Such pressures are felt acutely by developing states, whose capacity to comply can be severely restricted. Coming to grips with how best to strengthen local capacity and promote pronorm behavior is essential to the task of development and democratization.

Capacity building, institutional development, and norms of good governance matter not simply because they help level the playing field in trade, but because they strengthen domestic politics. In other studies, strong, capable bureaucracies have been shown to improve economic outcomes (Goldsmith 1999; Evans and Rauch 1999). They help a state resist corruption or arbitrary exercise of power on behalf of powerful interests, and they also outlive shifting political priorities. When public policy changes, bud gets are cut, or leaders forced out of office, bureaucracies that know how to apply rules fairly and make decisions based on accepted procedures will be healthier. Politicians will be less capable of forcing them to apply rules unequally or arbitrarily. Pro–rule of law attitudes imply that those responsible for enforcing rules take them as given and necessary. They enforce rules even when no one is looking—that is, when those responsible for scrutinizing public behavior are not watching. Conversely, weak rule of law undermines investment and growth, exacerbates poverty and security problems, and erodes public participation and trust. Rule of law is critical to economic success, social cohesion, and legitimacy (World Justice Project 2011; Americas Society and Council of the Americas 2007).

This book goes beyond a simple accounting exercise of resources devoted to enforcing the law and looks instead at whether and how a culture of rule of law has taken hold. Mexico clearly has a long way to go. Despite some improvements to the institutions of the state, a culture supportive of the rule of law has yet to be created. Without inclusivity, participation, transparency, consensus, and a sense of common ownership, the rule of law cannot root itself (United States Institute of Peace 2011; Finn 2004; Stromseth 2008, 2009). A culture of public trust and confidence in formal institutions is necessary.

Sadly, Mexico continues to suffer from widespread criminality and weaknesses in the justice system, where police, prosecutors, judges, lawyers, and the military can be unprofessional, poorly trained, and underpaid (Cornelius and Shirk 2007). In fact, the militarization of crime fighting may actually weaken other institutions, such as the police. One recent study showed that weak property rights and uncertainty about arbitrary confiscation lead to lower investment in productive activities by individuals and that Mexico needs in de pen dent, efficient, and trained judiciaries and bureaucracies; oversight mechanisms such as an ombudsman; and competitive elections by which political leaders are held accountable (Haber et al. 2008).

Regionalism and Domestic Political Change

Both external influences and domestic factors have an impact on how states make the transition from authoritarianism to democracy. Preexisting external links (such as ties to the West) can affect how regimes manage the transition (Levitsky and Way 2010). The role of external advocates and international organizations can also be influential (Keck and Sikkink 1998; Checkel 2005). Likewise, long-standing domestic practices are sometimes slow to change, even under pressure from outside. Rigid, politicized relationships based on particularistic advantage oft en obstruct reform and opening.

Regional agreements are important external sources of pressure. They can help foster domestic changes. They are crucial tools for development. However, our knowledge of how regionalism promotes development is limited, especially outside the Europe an Union (EU). The EU has helped its lagging member states and regions converge with the economic levels of its wealthy member states, and it distributes funding for these purposes through its structural funds. This contrasts with NAFTA, where guaranteeing market access is assumed to provide a sufficient engine of economic growth and development. There is no large-scale transfer of resources and no requirement to adopt an acquis communautaire or ensure democratic or human rights standards. The EU is a "welfare region," and NAFTA is a "market region" (to borrow from the lexicon of comparative political economy), and so the means by which they encourage development of their poorer member states differs. Unfortunately, however, we know very little about how the market region achieves its development aims, leaving us with no basis for comparison to other regions.

Because much of the U.S. opposition was based on the idea that free trade would cause race-to-the-bottom externalities, NAFTA is the first agreement to link trade opening with environmental and labor issues. Opponents assumed that heavily polluting industries would be encouraged to migrate to Mexico, which did not have the resources to enforce its own regulations or the willingness to raise standards (COHA 2007). Competition from China would undermine willingness to enact and enforce strict environmental controls. The negative effects of NAFTA were thought to be exacerbated by an investor rights provision, prohibiting subnational authorities in any member state from creating new barriers to investment, whether environmental or otherwise.

A counterargument claimed that free trade would lead to environmental benefits because productivity growth in sectors facing import competition creates efficiency gains and resource savings, a reduction in subsidies and other wasteful practices, and transfer of pollution prevention technologies (Galindo 2000: 186; Deere and Esty 2002: 3–4). According to one study, the most heavily polluting sectors were also the most protected, and opening up sectors to competition was likely to reduce pollution (Galindo, 2000: 186). Likewise, economic growth can lead to more resources being devoted to environmental protection.

However, empirical studies of the effect of NAFTA on Mexico's environment have yielded mixed results (cf. Gallagher 2004; Husted and Logsdon 1997). The studies use different methodologies, applied to different kinds of environmental questions, leading to widely varying results (Deere and Esty 2002: 12). Husted and Logsdon (1997) examined three periods immediately surrounding the entry into force of NAFTA (before 1990, 1990 to 1993, and after 1993) to determine whether environmental policies and regulatory standards were increased, whether enforcement was strengthened, whether behavioral standards among firms changed, and whether there were significant changes to environmental outcomes. Over this period, they found institutional strengthening and increased bud gets in Mexico.

Still, Gallagher found that environmental outcomes worsened measurably after NAFTA came into effect, mainly because neither the Mexican nor the U.S. government committed resources to tackle environmental problems (Gallagher 2004: 2). Compliance and enforcement remained a problem, and after 1993 (when NAFTA entered into effect) real spending and plant-level environmental inspections both fell significantly (Gallagher 2004: 9). Compared with other Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries, Mexico spends one third as much on the environment, controlling for gross domestic product (GDP) (Gallagher 2004: 71). Other assessments focus only on government compliance and fulfillment of treaty obligations (Deere and Esty 2002: 11). For example, Delgado and colleagues (2006) review Mexican environmental law and levels of pollution, as well as information on institutional responsibilities in the Secretariat for the Environment and Natural Resources (SEMARNAT). But they do not ask what the effect of the NAAEC has been on Mexico's capacity to solve environmental problems or on attitudes among civil servants.

(Continues...)



Excerpted from SIDE EFFECTS by Mark Aspinwall Copyright © 2013 by the Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University. Excerpted by permission of Stanford University Press. All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Table of Contents

List of Illustrations ix

Preface xi

List of Abbreviations xvii

1 A Tale of Two Side Agreements 1

2 Politicas Claras: Governing Mexico's Environment 26

3 Mordida Politics: Governing Mexico's Workplace 85

4 Governance and Attitude Change: Causes and Limits 136

Notes 175

References 183

Index 199

From the B&N Reads Blog

Customer Reviews